The Oxford Research Encyclopedia of International Studies will be available via subscription on April 26. Visit About to learn more, meet the editorial board, or recommend to your librarian.

Dismiss
Show Summary Details

Updated on 20 Nov 2017. The previous version of this content can be found here.
Page of

PRINTED FROM the OXFORD RESEARCH ENCYCLOPEDIA, INTERNATIONAL STUDIES (internationalstudies.oxfordre.com). (c) Oxford University Press USA, 2017. All Rights Reserved. Personal use only; commercial use is strictly prohibited (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 19 April 2018

World Trade Law

Summary and Keywords

After World War II, a body of rules and institutions have emerged for the purpose of regulating global flows of goods and services. These are known as world trade law, classified under international economic law, an expanding body of transnational regulatory treaties and institutions. World trade law has evolved within the global trading system following the Second World War, beginning with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which came into force in 1948. The Most-Favored Nation and National Treatment principles are the most prominent principles that give world trade law its distinctive form. The World Trade Organization (WTO) provides a vast store of literature which covers the waterfront of legal and political issues that animate the global political economy of trade. The WTO’s predecessor, the GATT, has also contributed extensively to the growing body of literature on world trade law. The WTO’s inclusion of agreements on the liberalization of services, investment, and intellectual property have begun lively debates about the possible trajectories of governance in new issue areas, such as anti-dumping and intellectual property rights. In addition to the issues raised by the inclusion of many small economies in the institutions of global trade governance, the rise of world trade law has simultaneously highlighted the many areas of importance to national publics in developed economies where trade overlaps with social priorities.

Keywords: world trade law, international economic law, GATT, WTO, Most-Favored Nation principle, National Treatment principle, global political economy, global trade governance, world trading system

Introduction

World trade law refers to the body of institutions and rules that have been created and nurtured following the Second World War to create an orderly legal environment with which to regulate global flows of goods and services (Charnovitz, 2011). While regional trade arrangements predate the 20th century, the current multilateral system is a more recent phenomenon, made possible by the postwar geopolitical context (Mazower, 2012). This article provides an overview of the most relevant interdisciplinary and international literature engaging with the study of world trade law. The first section offers a brief review of the literature, locating international economic law in an increasingly globalized world and answering the question of where trade law belongs in this larger sphere (McRae, 2009). The second section examines literature pertaining to the sources and functions of world trade law (Trebilcock & Howse, 2005). This includes work on the history of the postwar international legal system, the principles that underpin its organization, its major functional parameters, and a number of important institutional functions of the world trade institutions.

The third section continues this discussion of institutional development, reviewing key literature on governance issues at the WTO, examining the legal issues of antidumping and the enforcement of intellectual property rights alongside the political issue of integrating developing countries into the multilateral trade governance system (Nottage, 2009). Finally, the article reviews some of the most important literature that examines social priorities in the context of trade law. It is increasingly apparent to national governments and their voting constituencies that trading rules cannot be considered in isolation from social priorities, the most prominent of which are health, environmental standards, and cultural rights (Howse, 2002; Bartels, 2009). The article concludes with a brief discussion of the future of world trade law with respect to trade liberalization, dispute settlement, and the place of trade regulation in the larger context of international law. As the world trading system continues to evolve, so does the need for effective governance. The World Trade Organization has not become the engine of liberalization that it was designed to be, but it is becoming an essential legal arbiter in the regulation of international trade.

Relevant Literature Locating Trade Law in the International System

We may better understand the place of trade law in the more comprehensive system of international law by thinking of bodies of law as Russian nesting dolls. These bodies of law are not actually subsumed within one another, but rather exist alongside each other. Sometimes they overlap, and in other places their relationship is only now beginning to be defined (Charnovitz, 2002). However, the nesting doll metaphor is appropriate because it allows us to think about law deductively, moving from the largest sphere of international law to the most specific forms which that law may take. The largest doll may be considered the system of public international law. Public international law is the entire system of legal rules and customary practices that govern interactions between states (Kennedy, 2006). Currie suggests that “it may be useful to think of it as a legal system that applies where national legal systems leave off” (2001, p. 1).

Within this broad, incomplete, and sometimes fragmented international system lies a body of law frequently referred to as international economic law (Koskenniemmi, 2006). This expanding body of transnational regulatory treaties and institutions includes trade law; global and regional investment law; commercial law; and law pertaining to taxation, financial regulation, competition, and intellectual property (Guzman & Sykes, 2008). Much of this body of law exists beside (or perhaps overlaps with) domestic regulatory authority of states and offers a matrix of subnational, national, and international regulation that has grown more complex with the continuing pace of international economic integration. There is no consensus on the exact location of international economic law. In an instructive discussion, Charnovitz (2011) concludes that the place of international economic law in relation to other bodies of law, “namely, whether it is distinct from or overlapping with related bodies of law,” remains one of the “core doctrinal puzzles” that animates the study of international economic law (p. 22).

To complete the metaphor, the smallest doll is world trade law. Johnson (1998, p. 1) defines it as a body of law that has evolved within the global trading system following the Second World War, beginning with the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, which came into force on January 1, 1948. Lester, Mercurio, and Davies (2012, p. 3) agree, noting that the term itself is somewhat difficult to define because it is often used to refer to the larger body of international economic law as well as the agreements pertaining directly to the flow of goods and services across national borders. Most introductory legal textbooks therefore focus on the law as it relates to the “legal instruments that regulate trade flows.” Lester et al. suggest that trade law has historically been considered distinct from international law because it has been practiced by lawyers concerned with domestic regulation or by specialists on the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) based in Geneva (2012, p. 91). These practitioners formed what Howse (2002) calls a technocracy, operating below the radar, in a complex legal terrain seldom understood by outsiders.

Even so, with the rise in prominence of trade law following the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), an emerging epistemic community of scholars are increasingly interested in the possible ways in which international law may be interpreted in WTO law and vice versa (Bartels, 2001; Pauwelyn, 2001; Trachtman, 2004). Lester et al. examine a number of approaches to theorizing the place of trade law in the broader system of international law, concluding that there continues to be a general lack of clarity about the scope of international law in the trading system, which does not keep Members from referring to international law “whenever they believe it helps their arguments” (Lester et al., 2012, p. 109). Ultimately, the relative novelty of the legal system for trade, with its single undertaking for membership, reversed the consensus mechanism for the acceptance of dispute settlement panels and its expanded scope, which included governance mandates in services, investment, and intellectual property This situation created a thicket of complexity that legal scholars are analyzing, even as the system continues to evolve in the real world of trade governance (Lamy, 2006).

In the broad context of the social sciences, world trade is a multidisciplinary and highly pluralistic field of study with deep roots in the philosophical commonalities shared by politics and economics (Cropsey, 1960). While it is difficult to glean simplicity from the many theories and methods used to analyze the domestic and international goals, processes, and outcomes of trade law, three significant and timely issues are of concern here. The first is the importance of trade law to the cause of global development. Over time, scholars have begun to develop a more nuanced understanding of the domestic forces that drive international trade. Traditionally, economists have identified comparative advantage as the key driver behind the expansion of trade flows. However, as Helpman and Krugman have shown, “economies of scale provide an additional incentive and will give rise to trade even if countries are identical in tastes, technologies and factor endowments” (1999, p. 261).

Much has been made of these “spillover” effects of domestic markets, but the basic takeaway from the new trade theory of the 1980s is that market forces present within industrialized societies may intensify the incentive to trade, although significant incentives both in terms of growth and development are also present in less industrialized societies. Political scientists and legal scholars have taken the economic consensus on the benefits of trade seriously in the postwar system. Particularly in the study of trade law, the compatibility of open markets with economic development remains a major piece of the intellectual infrastructure that undergirds the multilateral project (Bhagwati, 2008; Dollar & Wade, 2009).

The second closely related issue concerns the impact of trade law upon global political interdependence. Much of the literature minimizes the possibility of an incommensurable fit between popular democracy and international trade regulation, while emphasizing the economic benefits of technological and economic integration (Abbott & Snidal, 1998). In much of the literature, national governments stand as an intervening variable between civil society and inter-governmental organizations, and this raises questions about the changing nature of the relations between national governance and trade regulation (Jackson, 2009). Previously, critics emphasized issues such as investor-state dispute settlement (Choi, 2007), but scholarship has evolved to include discussions of the impact of juridical mechanisms on participation in multilateral trade governance (Shaffer, 2009), the causes and consequences of regional trading arrangements (Krugman, 2013), and the impact of a hyperglobalized trading system on a number of issues ranging from climate change to currency wars and food security (Subramanian & Kessler, 2013).

The third point of discussion is about the place of trade law in global economic regulation (Hudec, 1999). Some scholars wonder whether the WTO is a constitution for world trade. Petersmann (2011, p. 53) defines a constitution as “a coherent set of long-term principles and rules of a higher legal rank constituting the basic order of a political community … or a functionally limited community.” In particular, do the current matrix of agreements and institutional processes embodied in the WTO comprise a constitutional order for global trade (Cass, 2005)? This question is fraught with definitional and conceptual pitfalls, as the literature aptly demonstrates (Dunoff, 2006). Is the WTO part of a political project by which trade rules are rendered legitimate (Pauwelyn, 2005)? This may indeed be the case, yet scholars are uncertain about whether it serves as an organizational frame for future liberalization and legalization processes (Howse & Nicolaidis, 2003). Certainly, as Trachtman (2006) points out, the WTO has a constitution in the legal sense of the term, but it remains unclear whether it operates as a constitution for legal activity in the global economic system, broadly defined.

The American legal scholars McGinnis and Movsesian (2000) offer another view of constitutionalism, arguing that the WTO does for its membership much of what the American constitution was designed to do for its states—repress factionalism, allow the free flow of goods, and set up the legal parameters for effective economic relations. The comparison between Madisonian constitutionalism and 21st-century trade governance is controversial, yet somewhat apt, at least if we do not stretch the comparison too far. Another way to consider the constitutionalism debate is in the critical context of Gramscian/Marxist discourse that views the World Trade Organization as an organizing rubric for the continued globalization of neoliberal economic policy (Gill, 1995). Critical social scientists argue that capitalist power relations are reified through legal systems and the institutionalization processes underway represent the globalization of a neoliberal economic order with outsize benefits for wealthy nations and their transnational firms (Cutler, 2003).

In certain functional ways the WTO does offer centralizing, aggregating and legitimizing functions (Evans, 2000). Slaughter (2003) has proposed an alternative to the constitutionalism metaphor by imagining a world of interconnected legal systems, in which the network of legal communities ought not to be considered an exemplary template, but rather a guide for future change. However, like the constitutionalism debate, the community of courts thesis suffers from a paucity of positive evidence, which does not invalidate the observation, but certainly calls for more research.

Literature on the Principles of World Trade Law and the Creation of the WTO

Scholars of world trade law begin their studies of the trading system with the principles that give the law its distinctive form, namely the Most-Favored Nation (MFN) and national treatment principles. These conceptual touchstones form the basis of much of the scholarship about trade governance and animate much discussion about the developmental trajectory of the multilateral trading system (Heiskanen, 2004). The MFN principle dates back to the Medieval period in the 12th century, and in the 18th and 19th centuries its inclusion in treaty arrangements occurred as a conditional clause, in which “benefits granted by one State were dependent on the granting of the same concessions by the beneficiary State” (UNCTAD, 2010, p. 10). Traditionally, MFN treatment required certain conditions to be met to trigger its benefits, and its inclusion in treaty arrangements required a substantial level of good will on the part of treaty signatories. As VanGrasstek notes, the granting of MFN was more often an exception rather than the rule of trade governance (2013, pp. 18–21).

Following the Second World War, MFN was defined to make the unconditional granting of MRN status the basis for membership in the GATT (Cottier, Mavroidis, & Blatter, 2000). Article I of the GATT 1947 declares that “any advantage, favour, privilege or immunity granted by any contracting party to any product originating in or destined for any other country shall be accorded immediately and unconditionally to the like product originating in or destined for the territories of all other contracting parties” The benefits of a multilateral application of MFN status are particularly important for developing countries and include transparency in the application of tariffs across all member jurisdictions, which gives smaller economies a trading advantage they would have otherwise been unlikely to negotiate with large trading partners (Aggarwal, 2006).

The second principle is national treatment. The principle of national treatment states that nations must treat imported goods the same way that they treat domestic goods for regulatory and taxation purposes. GATT 1947 Article III paragraph 1 states “The contracting parties recognize that internal taxes and other internal charges, and laws, regulations and requirements … should not be applied to imported or domestic products to afford protection to domestic production.” Like the MFN principle, the principle of national treatment is difficult to apply in the real world because while some protectionist regulations are obvious, much of what the state does to protect and enhance economic output occurs in the domain of business regulation. Even so, members have an obligation and must maintain law and policy in such a way as to minimize (and hopefully eliminate) substantive differences in the way domestic and imported goods are regulated (Ortino, 2005). These two principles give some sense of the complexity of bringing together the priorities of national governments and the demands of citizens with the multilateral standards for fair treatment of goods for trade.

Literature on the Creation of the WTO

In the closing days of the Second World War, questions of global economic coordination were largely considered within the context of international security and the orderly development of a system for global monetary relations (Eichengreen, 2008, pp. 91–100). This is not to say that the rehabilitation of global trade was not a distinct priority, but rather to emphasize the embedded nature of trade within a geopolitical context that emphasized security as the lynchpin of postwar growth and thereby foreshadowed the slow development of world trade law as it emerged as a body of law distinct from other forms of international economic law (Steil, 2013).

As the world’s leading economic power, the United States signed the GATT yet failed to ratify the International Trade Organization. This organization would have served as the governing institution for the world trading system, much as the World Bank and International Monetary Fund were designed to preside over postwar reconstruction and economic development (Irwin et al., 2009). Without an institutional home, the GATT remained in Jackson’s words, something of a “country cousin” to the international financial organizations in that it did not have the same profile upon the global political stage (Jackson, 1992, p. 11). Even so, the GATT was not without boosters, and its small secretariat hosted a number of liberalization rounds in the late 1940s and 1950s.

Winham has noted that the first four rounds did not reduce tariffs as much as expected due to the slow European recovery, but the United States did make several significant tariff concessions (2009, p. 16). The Kennedy (1963–1967), Tokyo (1973–1979) and Uruguay Rounds (1986–1994) made significant gains in the liberalization of trade and culminated in the creation of a multilateral institution for the governance of trade, inaugurated on January 1, 1995 (Croome, 1995; Ostry, 1997). The development of world trade law was driven by geopolitics and a high-minded belief that the principle of comparative advantage was the lynch pin for connecting wealth creation with peaceful global development, a dual economic and political rationale that has been discussed in Winham (1992) and Steger (2004).

The WTO was created to develop an institutional frame in the form of the secretariat to deal with the complexity of an international trading system in which more than a hundred countries had signed on to the GATT (McRae, 2009). A legal and institutional frame was necessary for the administration of new agreements brought into the trading system in the Uruguay round, in particular the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), the Agreement on Trade Related Investment Measures (TRIMS), and the Agreement on Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS). It was also increasingly apparent that the GATT’s dispute settlement measures were inadequate to the growing task of managing trade-related legal conflict, so a more robust legal system for the resolution of disputes was also needed (Weiler, 2000; Horn & Mavroidis, 2006; WTO, 2013).

VanGrasstek (2013, pp. 54–73) describes in great detail the negotiations that took place in the run up to the WTO’s birth. Professor John Jackson put forward a series of proposals part way through the Uruguay Round negotiations calling for a “World Trade Organization,” and describing its potential uses. His proposals were met with tepid support but were later championed by Debra Steger, a Canadian diplomat who had studied under Jackson and believed in the necessity of a new institutional mechanism for the administration of trade governance (Steger, 2004). The Canadian trade minister raised the issue with the European Union, which then championed the concept of a “multilateral trade organization,” which contrasted with the less formal mechanisms proposed by the United States for the administration of the new agreements currently under negotiation. In the final months of the Uruguay Round, horse-trading between the United States and the European Union saw the creation of a new institution with robust dispute settlement mechanisms in exchange for a wider mandate for trade governance and the understanding that the United States would stop using domestic courts to determine damages in international trade disputes, a practice that began as a stopgap measure but that was increasingly considered to be a conflict of interest by the international community. A description of the powers is contained in Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974.

Literature on Dispute Settlement at the WTO

With the creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO), several research spheres quickly developed around its institutional structure, the effectiveness of its processes, and mechanisms and the implications of its governance decisions (Shell, 1995; Koh, 1997). The largest of these research areas deals with the juridical mechanisms for the settlement of disputes. The Dispute Settlement Understanding (DSU) is by far the most distinctive legal mechanism to come out of trade multilateralism in the post-Cold War period (Bello, 1996). Dispute settlement at the GATT was nonbinding, and by the late 1980s, large trading powers such as the United States were turning to domestic courts to settle trade disputes. Such a move highlighted the need for a more robust set of rules for the settling of disputes at a forum that would remain free of the perception of political interference.

The DSU outlines a binding dispute settlement process, in which trade policies and practices are challenged before panels, which render a binding decision (Horn & Mavroidis, 2006; WTO, 2012). The panel’s final report may be appealed to an Appellate Body, which rules upon the substance and process of the original panel’s decision. More than 400 disputes have been remitted to the Dispute Settlement Body. As Leitner and Lester show, in the first 15 years of dispute settlement, 132 panels were circulated to the membership and 90 of those, or 68% were appealed (2011, p. 197). Several issues face the dispute settlement mechanism. Among the first to be highlighted is the fact that dispute settlement is expensive and its uptake happened much more quickly among industrialized nations with large trading volumes and significant experience with an adversarial court system modelled at least in part on the common law experience of Anglo-American members (Gao, 2007).

Dispute settlement raises the issue of conflicts between domestic authority and the authority of intergovernmental judicial panels. By adopting an appropriate standard of review, panels attempt to walk a fine line between the obligation of states to maintain their treaty obligations and the autonomy of governments to reflect in policy and law the interests of constituent voters. Pauwelyn (2003) has been one of the leading figures in this emerging field of scholarship with an important book examining this “conflict of laws.” Particularly in the first decade of governance, members worried that the broad scope of WTO governance would create a dynamic in which dispute settlement panels, whose decisions are binding for members, would delve too deeply into domestic regulation while rooting out protectionist policies.

To date, a minority of the WTO membership has used the dispute settlement mechanism, which may simply reflect the reality of global trade flows, or it may represent a significant gap in the skill sets or priorities of small economies (Bohanes & Garza, 2012). Much research has been conducted examining usage patterns (Hoekman, Horn, & Mavroidis, 2009; Froese, 2011), the potential benefits and drawbacks of usage (Keck & Schropp, 2007; Shaffer, 2009), and the possible implications for non-usage (Mosoti, 2006; Bown & Hoekman, 2007; Bown & McCulloch, 2010). Perhaps the most important finding highlighted by this research is the fact that legal capacity, measured in terms of access to knowledge, legal talent, and money, may account for some of the lack of uptake among poor countries (Busch, Reinhardt, & Shaffer, 2009). Other important questions remain about the ability of the DSM to effectively resolve disputes (Alter, 2003; McRae, 2008), both in terms to brokering an effective compromise as well as enforcing compliance with the binding decisions rendered by panels and the Appellate Body (Sullivan, 2003; van den Broek, 2003; Wilson, 2007).

Literature on Legal and Governance Issues at the WTO

The literature on the World Trade Organization’s (WTO’s) governance is vast, covering the waterfront of legal and political issues that animate the global political economy of trade. At its most basic, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is an agreement to lower tariffs, and the literature on tariffs, border measures and the use of quota systems for the regulation of imports grew exponentially over the 20th century (Schattschneider, 1935; Viner, 1952; Shonfield, 1976; Irwin, 2009). With the intensification of trade and the increasing recognition of global economic interdependence, the literature began to address a number of high-profile nontariff issues, such as dumping, subsidies, and safeguards (Vermulst & Graafsma, 2005). Trade in agricultural goods, which had been placed to one side in the GATT system because of its political sensitivity, has gained prominence at the WTO, if only because a development round that avoids agriculture is sidestepping one of the biggest trade issues facing exporters in developing economies (Clapp, 2006).

The WTO’s inclusion of agreements on the liberalization of services, investment, and intellectual property have inspired lively debates about the possible trajectories of governance in these new issue areas (Mercurio, 2004; Blouin, Drager, & Smith, 2005; Banerji & Jain, 2007). For the sake of simplicity, two issue areas that exemplify the ongoing debates about the possibilities and limits of multilateral trade agreements are discussed briefly—the research on antidumping and intellectual property rights.

Antidumping

Dumping occurs when a producer in Country A sells their product in Country B for less than the cost of production. This practice is usually used to clear a surplus without driving down the price in the home jurisdiction (Sykes, 1998). The primary defense against dumping is countervail—a set of escalating tariffs that may be implemented if a determination of dumping has been made. The main controversy surrounding the practice pertains to with the way in which determinations of dumping are made, and the subsequent employment of countervailing measures (Bourgeois, 1998). Critics of American antidumping laws argue that the Department of Commerce uses narrow windows of empirical evidence or controversial statistical methods to determine whether a product has been dumped on the American market (Froese, 2010). Of course, domestic producers and their powerful lobby groups also use dumping determinations to protect embattled domestic industries, such as American softwood producers (Devadoss & Roman, 2004). On the other side, producers and politicians frequently argue that the United States is one of the world’s largest and wealthiest markets, and foreign producers frequently use underhanded tactics to gain a share of this lucrative market (Mankiw & Swagel, 2005).

Globally, charges of dumping and the levelling of countervailing duties have become a basic strategy by which members of the WTO deal with the increasing intrasectoral competition faced by domestic producers (Drope & Hansen, 2006). As tariffs fall, nontariff barriers become an important tool for sheltering domestic industry. Dumping disputes are frequently brought to the WTO, where they are litigated under the Agreement on Anti-Dumping and the GATT. According to WTO statistics, 97 cases have cited the Article VI (Antidumping) of GATT 1994 in their requests for consultations, making dumping one of the most significant issues dealt with in dispute settlement. (Statistics related to the GATT dumping issue are available online.) There is a basic consensus among scholars and policy practitioners that excessive use of countervail protections is an unfortunate side effect of lower tariffs (Hudec, 1999; Bown, 2013). But there is little consensus on how to reduce the use of these and other nontariff barriers, and the extensive use of antidumping legislation continues to be one of the most significant features of the global trading system, one that was exacerbated by the 2008 financial crisis (Fritz & Wermelinger, 2009).

The Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights Agreement (TRIPS)

One of the main political trade-offs that typified the creation of the WTO was the tacit understanding between the United States on the one hand and the European Union and Canada on the other that if the United States wished to enlarge the scope of the GATT system’s governance of trade it would have to accept an enlargement of the institutional governance arrangements as well (VanGrasstek, 2013). Intellectual property rights were one of the highest-profile issue areas within this expanded governance domain (Drahos & Braithwaite, 2002). The rationale for the global protection of intellectual property is theoretically sound. If producers of intellectual property are to have an incentive to produce the processes, formulas and ideas that drive innovation, they must have a way to realize the profits of their efforts and this has traditionally been through a time-limited monopoly. National governments have traditionally governed the terms of this monopoly, and they have largely policed their own efforts through organizations such as the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO).

As Sell (2003) and others have noted, the placement of intellectual property inside the legal system for trade governance has resulted in a basic shift from national policing of intellectual property rights to multilateral policing, and from a negative (thou shalt not) form of rulemaking, to a positive (thou shall) form of rulemaking for the global governance of intellectual property rights. As many scholars have noted, these changes have significant implications for the governance of trade in intellectual property (Mercurio, 2004). Most notably, the TRIPS Agreement is one of a select few treaties under the WTO umbrella (the others being the Agreement on Trade Related Investment Measures and certain aspects of the Technical Barriers to Trade Agreement) that supplement the principles of nondiscrimination with a set of positive regulatory requirements. For example, TRIPS mandates the minimum length of time that a patent must be protected at 20 years.

Several scholars have pointed out the complications that arise from this form of multilateral policing (Drahos, 2003). They note that historically, the appropriation of intellectual property has been a major factor in economic development, pointing to ways in which American creators pirated patented material in the 19th and early 20th centuries, just as Chinese entrepreneurs do today (Lessig, 2004). Leaving aside the moral and economic implications of intellectual property theft, other scholars examine the institutional complications that arise from trade agreement designed to protect industrial property, which now has significant implications for access to medicines in the world’s poorest countries (Park, 2002; Curtis, 2012). Issues such as compulsory licensing of patented drugs and parallel importation for drugs produced outside the country have complicated the intellectual property rights issue and have made a relatively obscure aspect of regulation into a flashpoint for public anger over the perceived unfairness of the TRIPS Agreement for developing countries (George, 2011).

Literature on Trade Governance and Developing Countries

Perhaps the biggest single issue facing the trading system has been the inclusion of scores of developing countries, which bring very different concerns about the place of trade in development strategies than do the industrialized members who first created the GATT (Trommer, 2013). The discussions on the principles underpinning the trade system, new institutional mechanisms such as dispute settlement and the complications arising from new areas of governance such as intellectual property have significant implications for developing economies, as the literature adequately demonstrates. Nevertheless, we have not yet touched upon the issues directly related to the inclusion of developing country members into the WTO. This literature is specifically concerned with the development of “special and differential treatment” for developing countries, the use of dispute settlement by small economies, and the Doha Round of negotiations (Hoekman, 2004). The rise of regional forms of trade governance are also of significant importance for developing economies and have been covered in the entry “Formal International Institutions and the Regulation of Flows of Goods and Services.”

Special and differential treatment is the term used to identify the bundle of exceptions and differential timelines for liberalizations created for less developed and least-developed nations at the WTO. Recognizing that most of the membership is not fully industrialized, certain aspects of WTO negotiations divide the membership according to wealth and then apply trade discipline accordingly. In negotiation, the issues facing developing countries involve both order and magnitude (Clapp, 2006). In dispute settlement, the issues facing developing countries pertain to institutional access both in terms of financial and professional factors, as well as in terms of legal capacity (Bohanes & Garza, 2012). A minority of members use the DSM, and political scientists and trade lawyers examine the implications of nonuse of legal mechanisms (Smith, 2004). Successfully defending public policy and successfully challenging the protectionist policies of trading partners depends to a great extent upon the skilled use of the DSM (Shaffer, 2009). Trade lawyers note that effective use of dispute settlement mechanisms begins with continued use, which may aid in the development of professional standing and legal capacity on the part of civil servants (Hoekman, Horn, & Mavroidis, 2009).

Finally, the Doha Round of liberalization negotiations was supposed to place the issues of developing economies front and center at the WTO. However, after 12 years of negotiation, most negotiations remain far from complete. Significant political legitimacy may have been lost in the failure of the first trade round to prioritize developing country issues in the trading system (Akyuz, Milberg, & Wade, 2006). However, the failure of the Doha negotiations has resulted in the migration of many trade issues to the regional level, where agreements have proliferated (Stephenson, 2008). Even so, a multilateral approach to trade issues, from the liberalization of agriculture markets to the easing of barriers for trade in services, yields significant dividends because most developing country members do not have any other direct access to trade negotiations with the United States and the European Union outside the multilateral forum.

Literature Linking World Trade Law and Social Priorities

In addition to the issues raised by the inclusion of many small economies in the institutions of global trade governance, the rise of world trade law has simultaneously highlighted the many areas of importance to national publics in developed economies where trade overlaps with social priorities. The literature most often highlights issues relating to the environment, culture, labor standards, human rights, and health. Several of these issue areas—health, the environment, and cultural goods—are reviewed.

Trade Law and Public Health

National responsibilities for population health intersect with trade law in three basic areas. The first pertains to state regulatory autonomy. States may according to the law of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) limit trade in certain goods if the action is taken to protect human health. Even so, the protection of health through the limiting of trade is difficult because if the state is challenged in dispute settlement, it must show (among other factors) a clear chain of causation between its trade-limiting action and the health of the national population (McGrady, 2011, p. 164). France was able to show this chain of causation when it banned the importation of Canadian asbestos (Castleman, 2002), but the United States was not able to do so when it banned the importation of clove cigarettes from Indonesia for public health reasons, partly because the panel found that clove cigarettes are a similar product to menthol cigarettes produced in the United States. (A summary of the clove cigarettes case is provided online.)

The second has to do with new areas of multilateral regulation that broadened the WTO’s governance mandate after the Uruguay Round. In particular, scholars and policy makers have closely examined the implications of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) for public health (Blouin, Drager, & Smith, 2005). Health provision has been historically largely unaffected by trade, but with the birth of the GATS, it appeared as if the globalization of health service provision was upon us. This has not been the case, partly because member states have been unwilling to liberalize in these areas and partly because of low demand for cross-border medical service provision, although information and communication technologies has driven demand for some off-shoring in the information and communication technology (ICT) sector (Blouin et al., 2006).

Finally, there is the issue of intellectual property rights as they relate to public health. The TRIPS Agreement attempts to strike a balance between the needs of consumers and the rights of inventors to collect a fair return on their intellectual property. This balance has proven difficult to maintain, and the TRIPS Agreement is often considered to be one of the many stumbling blocks to equitable provision of medicines in countries facing health pandemics, such as that posed by HIV/Aids to countries in Africa (George, 2011). At the time it was drafted, TRIPS contained provisions to allow countries facing pandemics to temporarily suspend certain intellectual property rights to manufacture (at public expense) life-saving medicines—a process known as compulsory licensing (Wilson, Cawthorne, Ford, & Aongsonwang, 1999). But the basic problem was that most of the countries facing the HIV pandemic did not have any pharmaceutical manufacturing capacity.

With great difficulty, the TRIPS Agreement was eventually amended on December 6, 2005, to allow members with manufacturing capacity to fulfill the terms of the license. The first and only test of the new rules came in 2007, when Rwanda notified the WTO that it would seek the production of generic anti-retroviral medications from Canada. In institutional terms, the collaboration was a successful test of the new flexibilities. However, in practical terms, the legal, bureaucratic, and economic hurdles that must be surmounted to improve access to medicines are significant (Amollo, 2009). Although in fairness many of these hurdles are not the purview of world trade alone. The amendment became become a permanent piece of the agreement on January 23, 2017, when two thirds of the membership had accepted it.

Trade Law and the Environment

Even before the WTO came into being, national publics had begun to question the impact of multilateral trade regulation on environmental protection. In particular, the dolphin-tuna dispute in which the GATT struck down as discriminatory an American dolphin-safe labelling initiative for canned tuna, seemed to signal a new impatience within the multilateral trading order for domestic regulation protecting environmental priorities (Schoenbaum, 1997). The concern was then, and remains today, that environmental measures will be considered solely in terms of their potential trade distorting effects, rather than in terms of their possible impact upon environmental sustainability. A number of disputes have arisen in which World Trade Organization (WTO) panels have attempted to apply an appropriate standard of review that maintains the principles of Most-Favored Nation (MFN) and national treatment while simultaneously leaving room for national approaches to social priorities (Vranes, 2009).

Trade Law and Cultural Goods

Much has been made of the incommensurate differences between cultural products and industrial goods (Mas-Colell, 1999). Advocates of a cultural distinctiveness model for the treatment of cultural goods and services argue that a film cannot be treated in the same way as softwood lumber for example, both in the flow of the product in question across national borders as well as the basic form of regulation of the product behind the border (Throsby, 2001). There are three reasons for this. First, most cultural goods are increasingly digital, making their movement similar to financial flows than the import/export movement of commodities (Wunsch-Vincent, 2008). The preservation of intellectual property is an issue in this regard (Helfer, 2004). Second, the endless replication of these cultural goods raises concerns for the cultural producers in smaller economies that their industries will be swamped by high-quality, low-cost iterations from large economies, where cultural producers recoup the cost of production in their home jurisdiction and reap large profits in foreign markets (Grant & Wood, 2004). Examples include the sale and distribution of American cultural content such as films and magazines abroad. A number of disputes between Canada the United States have targeted this issue (Acheson & Maule, 1999).

Finally, cultural goods embody identities and social values in a way that industrial goods do not, contributing a number of complex sociocultural and political implications to their consumption (Drache & Froese, 2008). The WTO’s membership is deeply divided upon these issues, with producers in the United States arguing that consumers treat cultural goods much like any other product, consuming according to their tastes with little regard for national origins. A film may portray American social values, but many other products may be identified by the distinctive features and symbolic properties as well (Aageson, 2008). Even so, the cultural distinctiveness thesis has gained significant traction and provides a useful counterpoint to intellectual property when considering the relationship between trade governance and the global cultural economy (Sundara, 2008).

Conclusion: The Future of World Trade Law

The terrain of trade law is complex and prognostication is inherently risky, but it is possible to identify a number of potential trajectories for the development of international economic law. In particular, possible futures are identified in the literature regarding regional trade agreements, multilateral trade negotiation, dispute settlement, and the future role of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in the larger system of international law.

Regional trade agreements have proliferated exponentially in the years following the birth of the WTO, and while the trend has peaked in numerical terms, the future of integration likely lies at the regional level (Crawford & Fiorentino, 2005). This is not to deny the significance and rising juridical importance of the WTO, but rather point toward the number of increasingly large and complex arrangements currently under negotiation at the Transpacific Partnership (TPP), the E.U.-U.S. negotiations known as the Trans-Atlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP), and many others (Steger, 2012). The literature is split on the implications of the new regionalism, with some commentators seeing the rise of a particularism that undercuts the multilateral liberalization project (Bhagwati, 2007), while others see a compliment to the current trading system (Summers, 1991). They further argue that regionalism may offer a way to bypass the deadlock in the Doha Round while simultaneously offering multiple platforms upon which to test new institutional and legal mechanisms for governance (Stephenson, 2008). Critically minded scholars see the growing complexity of regional agreements as part of a neoliberal agenda that places the gains from trade ahead of workers’ rights and health, welfare, and environmental standards (De Ville & Siles-Brugge, 2015).

The future of multilateral trade negotiation is murky as scholars and practitioners debate whether the Doha Development Round is beyond revival, or whether portions of it may be saved to salvage a smaller deal (Bhagwati, 2011). In December 2013 one of these smaller deals was reached at the Bali Ministerial Conference, where negotiators came to an agreement on trade facilitation (Koopman & Wittig, 2014). Like the Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) amendment, the Trade Facilitation Agreement formally entered into force on February 22, 2017, once two thirds of the membership had ratified it. Ultimately, negotiators may be able to salvage a much smaller final package, and perhaps some negotiations may be spun off and completed as plurilateral agreements. But the big-tent form of trade multilateralism practiced immediately following the end of the Cold War is perhaps best understood as the unique product of an historical moment. At least two reasons for this are explored in the literature. First, the geopolitical dynamics of trade governance have shifted many new developing country members and the rising economic power of the so-called BRICS: Brazil, Russia, India, China, and South Africa (Narlikar, 2010). Second, the gains predicted at the end of the Uruguay Round (both in terms of governance effectiveness and economic advantage) have yet to fully materialize. This is partly because of turbulence in the global economy and is also due to ongoing complications related to internalizing and capitalizing upon disciplinary agreements, such as the TRIPS and new arenas of liberalization, such as the General Agreement on Trade Services (GATS).

Scholars are perhaps more sanguine about the future of the dispute settlement processes institutionalized in world trade law over the past 20 years. In terms of volume, the number of cases brought to the WTO peaked by 2000 (VanGrasstek, 2013, p. 54). But the dispute settlement mechanism continues to enjoy broad-based multilateral support. Daemmrich (2011) suggests that a shift has taken place in which the trading system used to derive a great deal of its legitimacy from its expanding membership base but has come to derive a similar legitimacy from its dispute resolution abilities. The novelty of binding rules and an appellate body have been replaced by debates about how to make dispute settlement more transparent and by discussions about how to integrate the interests of civil society into the process, which suggest a maturing organization. Concerns about the loss of sovereignty represented by a new international court have been mollified as concerns about the effective rates of compliance have been articulated (Plasai, 2007). In the final balance, the WTO’s developmental trajectory is trending away from liberalization negotiation and toward juridical and information gathering functions, suggesting a future in which the institution functions as a highly legitimate court, a lens for trade policy transparency, and a negotiating body with potential, but little kinetic energy (WTO, 2013).

The future of trade law within the broader system of public international law is likely to be one in which the many small challenges, conflicts, and overlaps within and between these bodies will continue to be addressed as they arise in the processes of treaty negotiation and dispute settlement (Baldwin, Kawai, & Wignaraja, 2013). Compromise will continue to be the rule, and now that a rationalization process is underway, it will continue to knit together the many disparate legal strands that compose the body of international economic law (Guzman & Sykes, 2008; Lester, 2013). The final outcome is likely to be a more coherent and focused body of trade law with a stronger understanding of its own strengths and limitations within the growing body of public international law that exists beyond the state.

Intergovernmental Organizations

The World Trade Organization produces statistical databases on global trade trends, reports on the state of trade policy around the world, and documentation relating to trade dispute settlement.

The WTO and Stanford University maintain an important cache of documents pertaining to the history of post-war trade governance at the GATT Digital Library: 1947-1994.

For UN reports and statistical databases relevant to developing country trade visit the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.

The United Nations Commission on International Trade Law website is a valuable resource.

The North American Free Trade Agreement Secretariat maintains databases of regional trade flows and documents pertaining to North American dispute settlement at https://www.nafta-sec-alena.org/Home/Dispute-Settlement/Overview-of-the-Dispute-Settlement-Provisions

Governmental and Region-Specific Resources

The Office of the United States Trade Representative is a valuable resource.

The United States Department of Commerce provides records for public access.

The Canadian Department of Foreign Affairs and International Trade maintains an online presence.

European Union’s online trade portal.

The Trade Law Center for Southern Africa offers a number of country briefs and working papers at https://www.tralac.org/.

University and Independent Research Sources

The Institute of International Economic Law at Georgetown University is a valuable resource.

The Trade Law Guide provides important information.

For introductory and advanced resources relating to the development of international economic law go to Lex Mercatoria.

For commentary on dispute settlement go to WorldTradeLaw.net.

Harvard University maintains a portal for research on global trade negotiations.

The Fletcher School at Tufts University maintains The Multilaterals Project, a full text database of international commercial treaties.

The Peterson Institute for International Economics maintains a large archive of research relating to trade law, investment, and competition.

The Cato Institute maintains material on a wide range of research relating to the globalization of international economic law.

References

Aageson, T. H. (2008). Cultural entrepreneurs: Producing cultural value and wealth. In H. Anheier & Y. R. Isar (Eds.), The cultural economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.Find this resource:

Abbott, F. M., & Snidal, D. (1998). Why states act through formal international institutions. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 42(1), 3–32.Find this resource:

Acheson, K., & Maule, C. (1999). Much ado about culture: North American trade disputes. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Find this resource:

Aggarwal, V. K. (2006). Bilateral trade agreements in the Asia-Pacific. In V. K. Aggarwal & S. Urata (Eds.), Bilateral trade agreements in the Asia-Pacific: Origins, evolution and implications. New York: Routledge.Find this resource:

Akyuz, Y., Milberg, W., & Wade, R. (2006). Developing countries and the collapse of the Doha Round: A forum. Challenge, 49(6), 6–19.Find this resource:

Alter, K. J. (2003). Resolving or exacerbating disputes? The WTO’s new dispute resolution system. International Affairs, 79(4), 783–800.Find this resource:

Amollo, R. (2009). Revisiting the TRIPS regime: Rwanda-Canadian ARV drug deal ‘tests’ the WTO General Council decision. African Journal of International & Comparative Law, 17(2), 240–269.Find this resource:

Baldwin, R., Kawai, M., & Wignaraja, G. (2013). Future of the world trading system: Asian perspectives.

Banerji, A., & Jain, T. (2007). WTO rules on investment: Futulity manifold. Journal of International Business Research, 6(2), 69–96.Find this resource:

Bartels, L. (2001). Applicable law in WTO dispute settlement proceedings. Journal of World Trade, 35(3), 499–519,Find this resource:

Bartels, L. (2009). Trade and human rights. In D. Bethlehem, D. McRae, R. Neufeld, & I. Van Damme (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international trade law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Barton, J., Goldstein, J., Josling, T., & Steinberg, R. (2006). The evolution of the trade regime: Politics, law, and the economics of the GATT and the WTO. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Find this resource:

Bello, J. H. (1996). The WTO dispute settlement understanding: Less is more. American Journal of International Law, 90(3), 416–418.Find this resource:

Bhagwati, J. (2007). The consensus for free trade—Has it frayed? Economic Research & Analysis.Find this resource:

Bhagwati, J. (2008). Termites in the trading system: How preferential agreements undermine free trade. New York: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Bhagwati, J. (2011). The Doha round’s premature obituary.

Blouin, C., Drager, N., & Smith, R. (Eds.). (2005). International trade in health services and the GATS: Current issues and debates. Washington, DC: World Bank.Find this resource:

Blouin, C., Gobrecht, J., Lethbridge, J., Singh, D., Smith, R., & Warner, D. (2006). Trade in Health Services under the four modes of supply: Review of current trends and policy issues. In C. Blouin, N. Drager, & R. Smith (Eds.), International trade in health services and the GATS: Current issues and debates. Washington, DC: World Bank.Find this resource:

Bohanes, J., & Garza, F. (2012). Going beyond stereotypes: Participation of developing countries in WTO dispute settlement. Trade, Law & Development, 4(1), 45–124.Find this resource:

Bourgeois, J. H. J. (1998). WTO dispute settlement in the field of anti-dumping law. Journal of International Economic Law, 1, 259–276.Find this resource:

Bown, C. P. (2013). How different are safeguards from antidumping? Evidence from US trade policies toward steel. World Bank Research Working Paper No. 6378.Find this resource:

Bown, C. P., & Hoekman, B. (2007) Making trade agreements relevant for poor countries: Why dispute settlement is not enough. Washington, DC: Brookings Global Economy & Development.Find this resource:

Bown, C. P., & McCulloch, R. (2010). Developing countries, dispute settlement, and the Advisory Centre on WTO law. World Bank Policy Research Working Papers. New York: World Bank.Find this resource:

Busch, M. L., Reinhardt, E., & Shaffer, G. C. (2009). Does legal capacity matter? A survey of WTO members. World Trade Review, 8(4).Find this resource:

Cass, D. Z. (2005). The constitutionalization of the World Trade Organization: Legitimacy, democracy and community in the international trading system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Castleman, B. (2002). WTO confidential: The case of asbestos. International Journal of Health Services, 32(3), 489–501.Find this resource:

Charnovitz, S. (2002). Triangulating the World Trade Organization. American Journal of International Law, 96(1), 28–55.Find this resource:

Charnovitz, S. (2011). What is international economic law? Journal of International Economic Law, 14(1), 3–22.Find this resource:

Choi, W.-M. (2007). The present and future of the investor-state dispute settlement paradigm. Journal of International Economic Law, 10(3), 725–747.Find this resource:

Clapp, J. (2006). WTO agriculture negotiations: Implications for the Global South. Third World Quarterly, 27(4), 563–577.Find this resource:

Cottier, T., Mavroidis, P. C., & Blatter, P. (Eds.). (2000). Regulatory barriers and the principle of non-discrimination in world trade law: Past, present and future. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Find this resource:

Crawford, J.-A., & Fiorentino, R. V. (2005). The changing landscape of regional trade agreements. WTO Discussion Papers. Geneva: World Trade Organization.Find this resource:

Croley, S. P., & Jackson, J. H. (1996). WTO dispute procedures, standard of review, and deference to national governments. American Journal of International Law, 90(2), 193–213.Find this resource:

Croome, J. (1995). Reshaping the world trading system: A history of the Uruguay round. Geneva: WTO Publications.Find this resource:

Cropsey, J. (1960). On the relation of political science and economics. American Political Science Review, 54(1), 3–14.Find this resource:

Curtis, J. M. (2012). Intellectual property rights and international trade: An overview.

Cutler, A. C. (2003). Private power and global authority: Transnational merchant law in the global political economy. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

Daemmrich, A. (2011). The evolving basis for legitimacy of the World Trade Organization: Dispute settlement and the rebalancing of global interests. Harvard Business School Working Papers No. 12–041.Find this resource:

Devadoss, S., & Roman, A. A. (2004). Recent developments in the US-Canadian softwood lumber disputes. Estey Centre Journal of International Law & Trade Policy, 5(2), 168–194.Find this resource:

De Ville, F., & Siles-Brugge, G. (2015). TTIP: The truth about the transatlantic trade and investment partnership. Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press.Find this resource:

Dollar, D., & Wade, R. H. (2009). Trade liberalization and economic growth: does trade liberalization contribute to economic prosperity? In P. M. Haas, J. A. Hird, & B. McBratney (Eds.), Controversies in globalization: Contending approaches to international relations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Congressional Quarterly Press.Find this resource:

Drache, D., & Froese, M. D. (2008). The global cultural economy: Power, citizenship and dissent. In H. Anheier & Y. R. Isar (Eds.), The cultural economy (pp. 52–66). Los Angeles: SAGE.Find this resource:

Drahos, P. (2003). When the weak bargain with the strong: Negotiations in the World Trade Organization. International Negotiation, 8, 79–109.Find this resource:

Drahos, P., & Braithwaite, J. (2002). Information feudalism: Who owns the knowledge economy? New York: New Press.Find this resource:

Drope, J. M., & Hansen, W. L. (2006). Antidumping’s happy birthday? World Economy, 28(3).Find this resource:

Dunoff, J. L. (2006). Constitutional conceits: The WTO’s constitution and the discipline of international law. European Journal of International Law, 17(3), 647–675.Find this resource:

Ehlermann, C.-D., & Lockhart, N. (2004). Standard of review in WTO law. Journal of International Economic Law, 7(3), 491–521.Find this resource:

Eichengreen, B. (2008). Globalizing capital: A history of the international monetary system. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Find this resource:

Evans, G. E. (2000). Lawmaking under the trade constitution: A study in legislating by the World Trade Organization. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.Find this resource:

Fritz, J., & Wermelinger, M. (2009). Has the crisis changed the use of antidumping? A comparative analysis. In The unrelenting pressure of protectionism: The 3rd GTA report (pp. 115–122). London, CEPR.Find this resource:

Froese, M. D. (2010). Canada at the WTO: Trade litigation and the future of public policy. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Find this resource:

Froese, M. D. (2011). Do rich countries ‘lawyer up’ faster than poor countries? Measuring the time from accession to first dispute at the WTO. Journal of World Trade, 45(6), 1237–1266.Find this resource:

Gao, H. S. (2007). China’s participation in the WTO: A lawyer’s perspective. Singapore Year Book of International Law, 11, 1–34.Find this resource:

George, E. (2011). The human right to health and HIV/AIDS: South Africa and South-South cooperation to reframe global intellectual property principles and promote access to essential medicines. Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 18(1), 167–197.Find this resource:

Gill, S. (1995). Constitutionalizing inequality and the clash of globalizations. Millenium, 23(3), 399–423.Find this resource:

Grant, P. S., & Wood, C. (2004). Blockbusters and trade wars: Popular culture in a globalized world. Toronto: Douglas & McIntyre.Find this resource:

Guzman, A., & Sykes, A. O. (2008). Research handbook in international economic law. London, Edward Elgar.Find this resource:

Heiskanen, V. (2004). The regulatory philosophy of international trade law. Journal of World Trade 38(1), 1–36.Find this resource:

Helfer, L. (2004). Regime shifting: The TRIPS agreement and new dynamics of international intellectual property lawmaking. Yale Journal of International Law, 29(1), 1–38.Find this resource:

Helpman, E., & Krugman, P. R. (1999). Market structure and foreign trade: Increasing returns, imperfect competition and the international economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Find this resource:

Hoekman, B. (2004). Developing countries and the WTO Doha round: Market access, rules and differential treatment. Journal of Economic Integration, 19(2), 205–229.Find this resource:

Hoekman, B., Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P. C. (2009). Winners and losers in the panel stage of the WTO dispute settlement system. In C. Thomas & J. Trachtman (Eds.), Developing countries in the WTO legal system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Horn, H., & Mavroidis, P. C. (2006). A survey of the literature on the WTO dispute settlement system. Social Science Research Network eLibrary, IFN Working Paper No. 684.Find this resource:

Howse, R. (2002). From politics to technocracy-and back again: The fate of the multilateral trading regime. American Journal of International Law, 96(1), 94–117.Find this resource:

Howse, R., & Nocolaidis, K. (2003). Enhancing WTO legitimacy: Constitutionalization of global subsidiarity? Governance: An International Journal of Policy, Administration & Institutions, 16(1), 73–94.Find this resource:

Hudec, R. (1999). Essays on the nature of international trade law. London: Cameron May.Find this resource:

Irwin, D. A. (2009). Free trade under fire, 3d ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Find this resource:

Irwin, D. A., Mavroidis, P. C., & Sykes, A. O. (2009). The genesis of the GATT. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

Jackson, J. H. (1992). GATT and the future of international trade institutions. Brooklyn Journal of International Law, 18, 25–26.Find this resource:

Jackson, J. H. (2009). The evolution of the world trading system—The legal and institutional context. In D. Bethlehem, D. McRae, R. Neufeld, & I. Van Damme, (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international trade law. New York: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Johnson, J. R. (1998). International trade law. Toronto: Irwin Law.Find this resource:

Keck, A., & Schropp, S. (2007). Indisputably essential: The economics of dispute settlement institutions in trade agreements. WTO Staff Working Paper, No. ERSD-2007-02.Find this resource:

Kennedy, P. (2006). The parliament of man: The past, present, and future of the United Nations. Toronto: HarperCollins.Find this resource:

Koh, H. H. (1997). “Why Do Nations Obey International Law?” The Yale Law Journal, 106(8), (Symposium: Group Conflict and the Constitution: Race, Sexuality, and Religion), 2599–2659.Find this resource:

Koopman, G., & Wittig, S. (2014). Whither WTO: The multilateral trading system after Bali. Intereconomics, 49(1), 2–3.Find this resource:

Koskenniemmi, M. (2006). Fragmentation of international law: Difficulties arising from the diversification and expansion of international law. Report of the Study Group of the International Law Commission. Geneva: United Nations International Law Commission.Find this resource:

Krugman, P. (2013). Interregional and international trade: Different causes, different trends?.

Lamy, P. (2006). The place of the WTO and its law in the international legal order. European Journal of International Law, 17(5), 969–984.Find this resource:

Leitner, K., & Lester, S. (2011). WTO dispute settlement 1995–2010: A statistical analysis. Journal of International Economic Law, 14(1), 191–201.Find this resource:

Lessig, L. (2004). Free culture: The nature and future of creativity. New York: Penguin.Find this resource:

Lester, S. (2013). The role of the international trade regime in global governance. UCLA Journal of International Legal & Foreign Affairs, 16(2).Find this resource:

Lester, S., Mercurio, B., & Davies, A. (2012). World trade law: Text, materials and commentary. Oxford: Hart.Find this resource:

Mankiw, N. G., & Swagel, P. L. (2005). Antidumping: The third rail of trade policy. Foreign Affairs, 84(4), 107–119.Find this resource:

Mas-Colell, A. (1999). Should cultural goods be treated differently? Journal of Cultural Economics, 23, 87–93.Find this resource:

Mazower, M. (2012). Governing the world: The history of an idea. New York, The Penguin Press.Find this resource:

McGinnis, J. O., & Movsesian, M. L. (2000). The World Trade Constitution. Harvard Law Review, 114(2), 511–605.Find this resource:

McGrady, B. (2011). Trade and public health: The WTO, tobacco, alcohol, and diet. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

McRae, D. (2008). Measuring the effectiveness of the WTO dispute settlement system. Asian Journal of WTO & International Health Law & Policy, 3(1), 1–20.Find this resource:

McRae, D. (2009). The place of the WTO in the international system. In D. Bethlehem, D. McRae, R. Neufeld & I. Van Damme (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international trade law. New York: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Mercurio, B. C. (2004). TRIPS, patents and access to life saving drugs in the developing world. Marquette Intellectual Property Law Review, 8(2), 211–250.Find this resource:

Mosoti, V. (2006). Africa in the first decade of WTO dispute settlement. Journal of International Economic Law, 9(2), 427–453.Find this resource:

Narlikar, A. (2010). New powers in the club: The challenges of global trade governance. International Affairs, 86(3), 717–728.Find this resource:

Nottage, H. (2009). Trade and development. In D. Bethlehem, D. McRae, R. Neufeld & I. Van Damme (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international trade law. New York: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Ortino, F. (2005). From ‘non-discrimination’ to ‘reasonableness’: A paradigm shift in international economic law? Jean Monnet Working Paper No. 01/05.Find this resource:

Ostry, S. (1997). The post-Cold War trading system: Who’s on first? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Find this resource:

Park, R. S. (2002). The international drug industry: What the future holds for South Africa’s HIV/AIDS patients. Minnesota Journal of Global Trade, 11(1), 125–154.Find this resource:

Pauwelyn, J. (2001). The role of public international law in the WTO: How far can we go? American Journal of International Law, 95(3), 535–578.Find this resource:

Pauwelyn, J. (2003). The limits of litigation: ‘americanization’ and negotiation in the settlement of WTO disputes. Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution, 19, 121–140.Find this resource:

Pauwelyn, J. (2005) The transformation of world trade. Duke Law Faculty Scholarship Paper No. 1229.Find this resource:

Petersmann, E.-U. (2011). International economic law, ‘public reason’, and the multilevel governance of interdependent public goods. Journal of International Economic Law, 14(1), 23–76.Find this resource:

Plasai, V. (2007). Compliance and remedies against non-compliance under the WTO system. ICTSD Project on Dispute Settlement Series.Find this resource:

Schattschneider, E. E. (1935). Politics, pressures and the tariff: A study of free private enterprise in pressure politics, as shown in the 1929–1930 revision of the tariff. New York: Prentice Hall.Find this resource:

Schoenbaum, T. J. (1997). International trade and protection of the environment: The continuing search for reconciliation. American Journal of International Law, 91(2), 268–313.Find this resource:

Secretariat, W. (2012). The WTO dispute settlement procedures: A collection of the relevant legal texts. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

Sell, S. K. (2003). Private power, public law: The globalization of intellectual property rights. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

Shaffer, G. C. (2009). Developing country use of the WTO dispute settlement system: Why it matters, the barriers posed. In J. Hartigan, (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO: An interdisciplinary assessment. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Find this resource:

Shell, G. R. (1995). Trade legalism and international relations theory: An analysis of the world trade organisation. Duke Law Journal, 44, 829–927.Find this resource:

Shonfield, A. (Ed.). (1976). International economic relations of the Western world, 1959–1971. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Slaughter, A.-M. (2003). A global community of courts. Harvard International Law Journal, 44(1), 191–219.Find this resource:

Smith, J. (2004). Inequality in international trade? Developing countries and institutional change in WTO dispute settlement. Review of International Political Economy, 11(3), 542–573.Find this resource:

Spamann, H. (2004). Standard of review for World Trade Organization panels in trade remedy cases: A critical analysis. Journal of World Trade, 38(3).Find this resource:

Steger, D. P. (2004). Peace through trade: Building the World Trade Organization. London: Cameron May.Find this resource:

Steger, D. P. (2012). WTO resilient but changed after ministerial meeting.

Steil, B. (2013). The battle of Bretton Woods: John Maynard Keynes, Harry Dexter White and the making of a new world order. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Find this resource:

Stephenson, S. M. (2008). New trade strategies in the Americas. In J. A. McKinney, & H. S. Gardner (Eds.), Economic Integration in the Americas. New York: Routledge.Find this resource:

Subramanian, A., & Kessler, M. (2013). The hyperglobalization of trade and its future. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.Find this resource:

Sullivan, H. D. (2003). Regional jet trade wars: Politics and compliance in WTO dispute resolution. Minnesota Journal of Global Trade, 12(1), 71–108.Find this resource:

Summers, L. (1991). Regionalism and the world trading system. Policy implications of trade and currency zones, a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (pp. 295–302). Jackson Hole, WY: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.Find this resource:

Sundara Rajan, M. T. (2008). Strange bedfellows: Law and culture in the digital age. In H. Anheier & Y. R. Isar (Eds.), The cultural economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE.Find this resource:

Sykes, A. O. (1998). Antidumping and antitrust: What problems does each address? In R. Lawrence (Ed.), Brookings Trade Forum 1998. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Find this resource:

Throsby, D. (2001). Economics and culture. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource:

Trachtman, J. (2004). Conflict of norms in public international law: How WTO law relates to other rules of international law by Joost Pauwelyn, review. American Journal of International Law, 98, 855–861.Find this resource:

Trachtman, J. (2006). The constitutions of the WTO. European Journal of International Law, 17(3), 623.Find this resource:

Trebilcock, M. J., & Howse, R. (2005). The regulation of international trade, 3d ed. New York: Routledge.Find this resource:

Trommer, S. (2013). Legal opportunity in trade negotiations: International law, opportunity structures and the political economy of trade agreements. New Political Economy, 1–20.Find this resource:

UNCTAD (2010). Most-favoured nation treatment: UNCTAD series on issues in international investment agreements II. New York: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.Find this resource:

van den Broek, N. (2003). Power paradoxes in enforcement and implementation of world trade organization dispute settlement reports: Interdisciplinary approaches and new proposals. Journal of World Trade, 37(1), 127–162.Find this resource:

VanGrasstek, C. (2013). The history and future of the World Trade Organization. Geneva: WTO Publications.Find this resource:

Vermulst, E. A., & Graafsma, F. (2005). WTO disputes: Anti-dumping, subsidies and safeguards. London: Cameron May.Find this resource:

Viner, J. (1952). International trade and economic development. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Find this resource:

Vranes, E. (2009). Trade and the environment: Fundamental issues in international law, WTO law, and legal theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

Weiler, J. H. H. (2000). The rule of lawyers and the ethos of diplomats: Reflections on the internal and external legitimacy of WTO dispute settlement. The Jean Monnet seminar and workshop on the European Union, NAFTA, and the WTO: Advanced issues in law and policy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Law School,Find this resource:

Wilson, B. (2007). Compliance by WTO members with adverse WTO dispute settlement rulings: The record to date. Journal of International Economic Law, 10(2), 397–403.Find this resource:

Wilson, D., Cawthorne, P., Ford, N., & Aongsonwang, S. (1999). Global trade and access to medicines: AIDS treatments in Thailand. Lancet, 354(9193), 1893–1895.Find this resource:

Winham, G. R. (1992). The evolution of international trade agreements. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Find this resource:

Winham, G. R. (2009). The evolution of the trading system—The economic and policy context. In D. Bethlehem, D. McRae, R. Neufeld, & I. Van Damme (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international trade law. New York: Oxford University Press.Find this resource:

World Trade Organization. (2012). Trade and public policies: A closer look at non-tariff measures in the 21st century.

World Trade Organization (2013). The future of trade: The challenges of convergence: Report of the panel on defining the future of trade convened by WTO Director-General Pascal Lamy. Defining the Future of Trade Series.Find this resource:

Wunsch-Vincent, S. (2008). Trade rules for the Digital Age. In M. Panizzon, N. Pohl, & P. Sauve (Eds.), GATS and the regulation of international trade in services. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Find this resource: